CLICK HERE FOR ITALIAN VERSION
London and the Emergence of a European Art Market, 1780-1820
Edited by Susanna Avery-Quash e Christian Huemer
Los Angeles, The Getty Research Institute, 2019
Review by Giovanni Mazzaferro. Part One
Los Angeles, The Getty Research Institute, 2019
Review by Giovanni Mazzaferro. Part One
The Getty Provenance Index©
Some preliminary information may be useful to the
reader. This volume includes the proceedings of the homonymous conference held
at the National Gallery in London between 21 and 22 June 2013. Some further contributions have however been added
to provide a more complete picture. Moreover, the conference was just one of
the highlights of a long-standing collaboration between the Getty Research
Institute and the National Gallery, two institutions particularly interested
in researching the formation and, above all, the origins of the relative
collections. Finally, the real protagonist of the volume is the Getty
Provenance Index©. Let us spend a few words on
it. The Getty Provenance Index© is a key digital tool (https://www.getty.edu/research/tools/provenance/search.html) which allows scholars to consult an
extensive series of documents including archive inventories, auction sales catalogues,
registers of commercial operators in the arts, payments to artists and descriptions
of museum public collections. The database is being constantly updated (for
example, very recently data about 6,000 publications relating to the German
auctions held between 1900 and 1945 have been included in the section dedicated
to sales catalogues).
Precisely basing itself on the Getty Provenance
Index©, the work aimed at deepening the understanding of a known
phenomenon, on which however much still needs to be written about: The
replacement of Paris with London in the years between 1780 and 1820 as the
'capital' of the art trade in Europe. This was clearly a consequence of the
historical events of the time, and in particular of the outbreak of the French
Revolution (1789), of the convulsive years culminating in the Terror, of
Napoleon's rise to power, of his triumph and, finally, of his fall. All this -
it is good to remember - happened in substantial coincidence with other events
such as the requisition of works of art
by the French armies,
the creation of the Louvre and its transformation into the Musée Napoléon
(1802) and the (partial) recovery of the
works stolen after restoration.
The really enriching aspect of the conference
(and therefore also of the volume) is the tangible demonstration that the
examination of the data contained in the Getty Provenance Index© may
indeed lead to a multiplicity of diverse analytical approaches. To have an
order of magnitude, the counting of the sales catalogues has led to the
registration of almost 250 thousand
items, which were auctioned between 1680 and 1800. Of them, over 100
thousand were sold during the twenty years 1780-1800. Quantitative surveys
(working on such large datasets) can therefore be combined with others more
qualitative approaches (e.g. traditionally examining the development of
individual collections or the work of intermediaries involved in the business).
Precisely for this reason the volume was
divided into three sections: ‘Models’, ‘Collections’, ‘Intermediaries’. By and
large, I will stick to this structure in illustrating the contents. A final caveat
is necessary: Is it really possible to establish precisely what was the portion
of sales processed though auctions in Europe compared to the overall trade in
artistic artefacts? The issue is very complex. In this regard, the volume
quotes a research by Guido Guerzoni (which I was not able to read yet)
according to which, in the period under consideration, auction sales may have represented
roughly 20%-25% of total turnover [1]. Some aspects, however, are not clear to
me. Did this (already very substantial) share also include the so-called 'private
contract' sales which were 'invented' by Noël Desenfans in 1786? The latter were
highly successful in the following years (think of the dispersion of the
Orléans Collection, considered the event that symbolically delivered to London
the sceptre of 'queen of the European market'). Prima facie, it would seem they
did not. If this is the case, it is clear that the percentage of transactions
surveyed by the Getty Provenance Index© is even more consistent, and
therefore even more representative of reality.
![]() |
Jean-Baptiste-Pierre Le Brun, Self-Portrait, 1795, private collection Source: https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:Jean-Baptiste-Pierre_Le_Brun_1796.jpg |
Index of Part I - Models
- Neil De Marchi, Introduction to Part One;
- Peter Carpreau, English and French Auctions in a Troubled Period, 1780-1820. A Quantitative Analysis of Volume, Price, and Taste Based on the Getty Provenance Index© Databases;
- Bénédicte Miyamoto, British Buying Patterns at Auction Sales, 1780-1800. Did the Influx of European Art Have an Impact on the British Public’s Preferences?;
- Hans J. van Miegroet, Hilary Cronheim, Bénédicte Miyamoto, International Dealer Networks and Triangular Art Trade Between Paris, Amsterdam, and London;
- Guido Guerzoni, The Export of Works of Art from Italy to the United Kingdom, 1792-1830;
- Olivier Bonfait, The Taste for Eighteenth-Century French Paintings. Internazionalitation and Homogenization of Demand on the London Art Market around 1800.
The
index of normalized prices
The section
dedicated to 'Models' is undoubtedly the most intriguing, in terms of innovation.
It shows how socio-economic models can help interpret facts and grasp reality,
if combined with the consultation of the Big Data of the Getty Provenance Index©.
Of course we do not pretend to explain everything with figures; however (while
sometimes the contradictions between one contribution and another are evident) the
research paths are obviously very interesting, as the research on the economic facets
of art largely prevails over the purely
stylistic aspects.
Peter
Carpreau’s avenue seems particularly striking to me. Carpreau took into
consideration the auctions held in France and England between 1780 and 1820; he
highlighted their progress in volumes and prices (those in France dropped
drastically in the revolutionary period, but showed a recovery in the second
decade of the nineteenth century); above all, he tried to investigate the level
of sales prices (very often available in the Getty Provenance Index©),
using the concept of 'normalized price'. What is a "normalized
price"? A comparable price in different geographical and institutional
frameworks because it is not affected by inflationary phenomena, but also by
aspects such as different developments in term of real growth and so on.
To obtain
this, Carpreau considered the list of prices at which the works were awarded
and calculated not the arithmetic average, but the median, or the intermediate
value of the auction prices. In fact,he explained that averages are not very
reliable for at least two reasons: the auction prices were not distributed
according to a 'normal curve', because below a certain level the works were
withdrawn from the auction and were not awarded; moreover, the arithmetic mean,
statistically, was too influenced by the tales, and in particular by extreme
high values in this case. He then transformed the median expressed in local
currency into gold (which he considered an asset with a less fluctuating
value). Then he divided each auction price (expressed in gold) precisely with
the median of the prices contained in the database, also converted into gold.
The resulting value is a normalized price, which Carpreau considers the true “price
of taste", because it would only express the evolution of taste on
individual markets. I am not entirely sure - I will be sincere - that taste is
really the only element that affected this value; I am thinking, for example,
that the price level could be artificially affected by speculative upward
pressures due to the specific behavioural dynamics on the demand side during
the bidding (or, on the contrary, to cartel agreements on the supply side to
limit prices) [2].
The results
(to be considered with the benefit of the doubt [3]) are that in the last
twenty years of the eighteenth century the average level of 'normalized' price were
constantly higher in France than in England (curiously with a peak in 1795),
while in the first twenties of the nineteenth century the outcome was completely
reversed to the advantage of price levels in the English markets. As far as
business volumes are concerned, the "turnover" in France was severely
affected already at a much earlier date, so that the English predominance became
evident as from 1785, while France was able to partially catch-up only from
1810 onwards.
![]() |
Thomas Gainsborough, Portrait of James Christie, 1778, Los Angeles, J. Paul Getty Museum Source: The J. Paul Getty Museum, Getty's Open Conten Program |
Debunking
a common place
The handover
in the artistic market dominance between Paris and London was symbolically
represented by the dispersion of the Orléans collection, which took place in
two stages, i.e. in 1793 (for northern European artworks) and 1798 (for Italian
paintings). However, these events, and in particular the second sale, were attributed
an additional and questionable reading. William Buchanan (1777-1864), for
example, in his Memoirs of Painting: With a Chronological History of the
Importation of Pictures by the Great Masters into England since the French
Revolution (London, 1824) argued that nothing, after the dispersion of the
collection Orléans, could ever remain intact in the future: The world of
English collectors, in fact, had discovered the Ancient Italian Masters at the
expense of the schools of Northern Europe. As an art dealer Buchanan had a
conflict of interest. In fact, he did not hesitate to attribute himself, at
least in part, the origin of this turning point in taste. Crucially, he was also
a convinced neoclassicist, and he read the change of British aesthetic
preferences as a form of artistic progress, with the alignment with the canons
of beauty that had already conquered all of Europe. One of Bénédicte Miyamoto's
aims was to understand, on the basis of the quantitative analysis of data, whether
a discontinuity of this kind really existed; that is, whether changes in the
European artistic taste really had such a sudden and effective influenced on the
Anglo-Saxon public. The result is clear-cut: it was not so. Examining the sales
data between 1767-1789 and 1790-1800 it is clear that the deviations were
minimal: indeed, Dutch and Italian art (which already had a predominant
cumulative position, with almost 60% of the paintings sold) both fell slightly
to advantage of Flemish, French, German and Spanish production; but, I would
like to stress it again, the differences were, in percentage terms, really
insignificant. Moreover, also the distribution of works by genre remained
(almost) unchanged (although it may be difficult to assign works to genres on
the simple basis of titles of paintings that have been destroyed or lost), with
a clear predominance of landscape over history painting (Italian painting was
especially associated to the latter, which represented around one third of the
full production). Miyamoto's conclusions were that, in the years of the
dispersion of the Orléans collection, the London art market was "mature":
market participants had already had the opportunity to fully unfold their
preferences, which would be widely confirmed later.
![]() |
Claude Lorrain, Landscape with Hagar and the Angel, 1646, London, The National Gallery Source: The National Gallery, Creative Commons Agreement |
Grasping the integration of markets
Was there a
"globalization" of the art markets at the turn of the eighteenth and
nineteenth centuries? The question is far from trivial, especially considering
the war events that overwhelmed Europe in the years from the French Revolution
to the Restoration. If this globalization existed, to what extent were the
markets homogeneous? In essence, the essays by Hans J. van Miegroet, Hilary
Cronheim and Bénédicte Miyamoto on one side and Olivier Bonfait on the other were
dedicated to this theme. It is beyond dispute that, starting in the
mid-eighteenth century, some merchants were systematically buying Dutch
paintings at low prices in Amsterdam, and then selling them at a higher price, at
first only in Paris and, later on, also in London. The authors of International
Dealer Networks and Triangular Art Trade elaborated data relating to the
Amsterdam market and noted that prices had remained substantially stable during
the second eighteenth century: The Dutch market was structurally favouring
buyers, and between them, those whose business model was to sell at higher
prices elsewhere. Against this, the same works resold in Paris, from 1745
onwards, had there higher prices.
Among the
operators commuting between Amsterdam and Paris (and later London) I would like
to mention Jean-Baptiste-Pierre Lebrun (1748-1813), who in 1802 wrote he had
been in Holland at least forty times just to purchase a portfolio of paintings.
Lebrun turned out to be a fundamental figure for at least two reasons: the
first is that he perfected in Paris mercantile practices linked to auction
sales such as the insertion of newspaper advertisements and the drafting of
ever more exhaustive catalogues, in which he did not simply listed works, but
described them and indicated their origin (it is proven that indicating a
painting as of Dutch school was making it much more likely to sell at a higher
price); the second is that Lebrun was the first to test the London market and
to introduce such "good practices" in London, also thanks to the
collaboration of a new generation of "self-made men" who were approaching
the profession. One of these was Noël-Jospeh Desenfans (1744-1807) who became
an agent by chance and without any particular knowledge in the arts, but knew
how to build a solid professional reputation over the decades. The role of the
merchant, especially in the last two decades of the eighteenth century, required
a preparation combining commercial practices and a specific stylistic
knowledge: connoisseurship was the natural result of this type of requirement.
If the
Dutch, French and English markets proved to be interrelated (and one of the
aspects that most demonstrated was the birth of a real 'calendar' of auctions,
without overlaps, so that professional operators could participate in all the
scheduled appointments), the problem that Olivier Bonfait raised is whether
(with reference to Paris and London), this also corresponded to a substantial
homogenization of taste. The answer (again based on the price values achieved
at the auctions and present in the Getty Provenance Index©) was
negative: in this context, every market still tent to maintain its own
peculiarities. While it is all in all logical that the French and English
artists had respectively more success in their respective homelands, it appears
instead indicative that, among the French artists, those most appreciated in
Great Britain best corresponded to the taste preferences already practiced by
the English, that is exponents of the painting of gender and landscape
painters. An "internationalization" of the markets, in short, did not
automatically mean a "homogenization" of taste.
![]() |
Claude-Joseph Vernet, A Sporting Contest on the Tiber, 1750, London, The National Gallery Source: The National Gallery, Creative Commons Agreement |
Imports from Italy
I really
regret that the contribution on which I must point out the most reservations is
precisely that of an Italian, Guido Guerzoni, who dealt with the export of
works of art from Italy to England between 1792 and 1830. I will
make a premise: Guerzoni has been dealing with the subject for years. Suffice
it to mention his Prolegomeni per uno studio del mercato artistico
tra Sette ed Ottocento (Introduction
to a study of the art market between the XVIII and the XIX century) in Giovanni Battista Cavalcaselle conoscitore e conservatore, curated by Anna Chiara Tommasi, Venice, Marsilio, 1998.
Also with Marsilio, in 2006, he published Apollo e Vulcano. I mercati artistici in Italia (1400-1700), later (2011) translated into
English as Apollo and Vulcan. The art markets in Italy (1400-1700) (East Lansing, Michigan State University Press). Honestly, I
have not been able to read either the Italian version of the work (which, with
great courtesy, the author sent me at my request) or the English one; I am planning
to do it and, for the moment, I am presenting my considerations with all
necessary caution. Very effectively, Guerzoni summarized the issues related to
the dispersion of Italian works of art and their protection by the
pre-unification states. However, sometimes, in my opinion, he made some
statements that apparently are not supported either by data or by literature:
it is, for example, a simple conjecture that most of the works sold at
Napoleonic auctions (of which we know nothing, because no catalogues were
compiled, also because these auctions addressed works judged to be
"discarded") ended up in the hands of Italian buyers who then put
them back onto the market calmly in the following years. The problem is that we
have no certainty on this. As to Vincenzo Bratti (to whom reference is made) we
know that in 1811 he bought 1305 paintings for 791 lire at a public auction in
Venice, but we ignore how he sold them. Particularly unfortunate, then, is the quote of Pietro Edwards, who, following a consolidated but wrong tradition, is indicated as one of the great buyers of the works put up for auctions. I have
personally seen all the papers relating to Pietro Edwards in Venice and, without denying
his involvement in the market in the years before the fall of the Republic, it
can be shown that, under Napoleon, he pursued a project to create a gallery of
exclusively Venetian works ordered by complete historical series. He tried,
therefore, to select and save from the enormous mass of paintings made free by the
Napoleonic suppression of religious orders all what he considered capable of
documenting the evolution of Venetian painting (having certainly in mind Della
pittura veneziana by Anton
Maria Zanetti the younger of 1771). Concerning all other works, he pleaded in
favour of their destruction (as Cicognara did) in order not to reduce the economic
value of the patrimony of the Venetian patricians and not to lower the level of
prices to the detriment of contemporary artists. A speculator would not have
reasoned so [4].
But the
most problematic aspect seems to me the explanation of the data that illustrate
the quantities of artistic products imported from four Italian states (Grand
Duchy of Tuscany, State of the Church, Kingdom of the Two Sicilies,
Lombard-Veneto - obviously as part of the Austro-Hungarian Empire) in England
between 1820 and 1840. The data are taken from the registers of English
customs, a source of undoubted interest. They confirm an aspect that,
qualitatively, we already know: The export restrictions in some
realities administrative, for example in the Papal States, where the Pacca
edict had been in operation since 1820, was making the export of assets more
difficult. However,
it is enough to compare the data relating to the exports of paintings merely
from Tuscany and the Papal States to get doubts about these figures.
Below I am reporting the data relating with the Grand Duchy of Tuscany and the Papal State, with the warning that these are simply the
numerical series relating to the individual years in progression (therefore
1820, 1821 etc.)
Grand Duchy
of Tuscany: 429; 331; 316; 294; 407; 550; 680; 768; 1681; 1933; 1678; 1204;
1114; 1355; 1511; 1346; 1820; 2216; 2206; 2791; 3407.
Papal
State: 9; 0; 0; 3; 0; 0; 0; 0; 3; 0; 0; 0; 74; 6; 0; 0; 0; 23; 0; 10; 109.
It is
enough to compare these data with the chronicles that complain about the
continuous plundering in those years in the State of the Church (I have in mind
those from Bologna) to suppose (even net of smuggling) that there may be a
quality problem with the data. And, in particular, there is a strong doubt that
the English customs (as appears logical) did not record the original provenance
of the artworks, but the place from which they were shipped; and that for tax,
but above all logistic reasons, the British preferred to send what they had
bought in Italy from the port of Livorno, where their presence was consolidated
for centuries. Moreover, if still in 1858 Charles Lock Eastlake preferred to
send two paintings bought from the Ferrara-based Costabili collection via
Livorno, there must have been compelling reasons, which should be investigated [5].
In conclusion, although I do not know precisely those reasons, it seems to me
extremely probable that the data of British customs do not correctly photograph
the reality of the Ancient Italian States, which are distorted by questions related to
the shipping of goods.
NOTES
[1] British Buying Patterns at
Auction Sales, 1780-1800. Did the Influx of European Art Have an Impact on the
British Public’s Preferences? in London and the Emergence of a European
Art Market, 1780-1820, edited
by Susanna Avery-Quash and Christian Huemer, p. 37.
[2] To be clearer, my doubt is that a
'dominant' market at a given time must be 'structurally' more aggressive, and
above all 'differently' speculative than the others. For example, Paris may
have been more speculative in the eighties of the eighteenth century and London
in the second decade of the nineteenth century. I have no 'evidence' to confirm
this topic. I only say that this aspect could affect the ratio of normalized
prices between the two markets, negating a reading of the normalized price as a
simple matter of "taste".
[3] The author, for obvious reasons of space,
summarized in a few pages the features of his research, but without concretely
explaining how (for example) he produced the conversion between the individual
currencies and the value of gold. I am careful not to question the seriousness
of his studies. However, I am pointing out that the reader, devoid of major
interpretative elements, must dutifully accept these theses with the benefit of the doubt.
[4] Allow me to refer to G. Mazzaferro, Fra Repubblica, Napoleone e Impero Austriaco. Pietro Edwards Ispettore Generale alle Belle Arte in "ABAV Annuario dell'Accademia di Belle Arti di Venezia 2015", curated by Alberto Giorgio
Cassani, Bari-Rome, Editori Laterza.
[5] See the letter of Charles Lock Eastlake to
the marquis Costabili of October 26, 1858: "Dear Sir, Mr Michelangelo Gualandi wrote me from Bologna that the box with the two known pictures has
been sent to Livorno, and I hope it will happily reach London”. See Jaynie
Anderson, The Restoration of Renaissance Painting in mid Nineteenth-Century
Milan. Giuseppe Molteni in Correspondence with Giovanni Morelli, Florence, Edifir, 2014, p. 35 n.
18.
Nessun commento:
Posta un commento